4.3 – Labour-Leisure Choices

Learning Objectives

  • Interpret labour-leisure budget constraint graphs
  • Predict consumer choices based on wages and other compensation
  • Explain the backward-bending supply curve of labour

 

People do not obtain utility just from products they purchase. They also obtain utility from leisure time. Leisure time is time not spent at work. The decision-making process of a utility-maximizing household applies to what quantity of hours to work in much the same way that it applies to purchases of goods and services. Choices made along the labour-leisure budget constraint, as wages shift, provide the logical underpinning for the labour supply curve. The discussion also offers some insights about the range of possible reactions when people receive higher wages, and specifically about the claim that if people are paid higher wages, they will work a greater quantity of hours—assuming that they have a say in the matter.

According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. workers averaged 38.6 hours per week on the job in 2014. This average includes part-time workers; for full-time workers only, the average was 42.5 hours per week. Table 6.4.1 shows that more than half of all workers are on the job 35 to 48 hours per week, but significant proportions work more or less than this amount.

Table 4.3a breaks down the average hourly compensation received by private industry workers, including wages and benefits. Wages and salaries are about three-quarters of total compensation received by workers; the rest is in the form of health insurance, vacation pay, and other benefits. The compensation workers receive differs for many reasons, including experience, education, skill, talent, membership in a laboir union, and the presence of discrimination against certain groups in the labour market.

Table 4.3a Persons at Work, by Average Hours Worked per Week in 2013 (Total number of workers: 137.7 million)(Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2022a)
Hours Worked per Week Number of Workers Percentage of Workforce
1–14 hours 6.9 million 5.0%
15–34 hours 27.6 million 20.1%
35–40 hours 68.5 million 49.9%
41–48 hours 11.9 million 8.6%
49–59 hours 13.3 million 9.6%
60 hours and over 9.3 million 6.8%
Table 4.3b Hourly Compensation: Wages, Benefits, and Taxes in 2014 (Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2022b)
Compensation, Wage, Salary, and Benefits $30.92 per hour
Wages and Salaries $20.92
Benefits
Vacation $2.09
Supplemental Pay $0.84
Insurance $2.15
Health Benefits $2.36
Retirement and Savings $1.24
Defined Benefit $0.57
Defined Contribution $0.064
Legally Required $2.46

The Labour-Leisure Budget Constraint

How do workers make decisions about the number of hours to work? Again, let’s proceed with a concrete example. The economic logic is precisely the same as in the case of a consumption choice budget constraint, but the labels are different on a labour-leisure budget constraint.

Vivian has 70 hours per week that she could devote either to work or to leisure, and her wage is  $10/hour. The lower budget constraint in Figure 4.3a shows Vivian’s possible choices. The horizontal axis of this diagram measures both leisure and labour, by showing how Vivian’s time is divided between leisure and labour. Hours of leisure are measured from left to right on the horizontal axis, while hours of labour are measured from right to left. Vivian will compare choices along this budget constraint, ranging from 70 hours of leisure and no income at point S to zero hours of leisure and $700 of income at point L. She will choose the point that provides her with the highest total utility. For this example, let’s assume that Vivian’s utility-maximizing choice occurs at Point O, with 30 hours of leisure, 40 hours of work, and $400 in weekly income.

Figure 4.3a How a Rise in Wages Alters the Utility-Maximizing Choice. How a Rise in Wages Alters the Utility-Maximizing Choice by OpenStax, licensed under CC BY 4.0.

Figure 4.3a, How a Rise in Wages Alters the Utility-Maximizing Choice, shows Vivian’s original choice is Point O on the lower opportunity set. A rise in her wage causes her opportunity set to swing upward. In response to the increase in wages, Vivian can make a range of different choices available to her: a choice like Point D, which involves less work; and a choice like Point B, which involves the same amount of work but more income; or a choice like Point A, which involves more work and considerably more income. Vivian’s personal preferences will determine which choice she makes.

For Vivian to discover the labour-leisure choice that will maximize her utility, she does not have to place numerical values on the total and marginal utility that she would receive from every level of income and leisure. All that really matters is that Vivian can compare, in her own mind, whether she would prefer more leisure or more income, given the tradeoffs she faces. If Vivian can say to herself: “I’d really rather work a little less and have more leisure, even if it means less income,” or “I’d be willing to work more hours to make some extra income,” then as she gradually moves in the direction of her preferences, she will seek out the utility-maximizing choice on her labour-leisure budget constraint.

Now imagine that Vivian’s wage level increases to $12/hour. A higher wage will mean a new budget constraint that tilts up more steeply; conversely, a lower wage would have led to a new budget constraint that was flatter. How will a change in the wage and the corresponding shift in the budget constraint affect Vivian’s decisions about how many hours to work?

Vivian’s choices of quantity of hours to work and income along her new budget constraint can be divided into several categories, using the dashed horizontal and vertical lines in Figure 4.3a that go through her original choice (Point O). One set of choices in the upper-left portion of the new budget constraint involves more hours of work (that is, less leisure) and more income, at a point like A with 20 hours of leisure, 50 hours of work, and $600 of income (that is, 50 hours of work multiplied by the new wage of $12 per hour). A second choice would be to work exactly the same 40 hours, and to take the benefits of the higher wage in the form of income that would now be $480, at choice  Point B. A third choice would involve more leisure and the same income at point C (that is, [latex]33-1/3[/latex]) hours of work multiplied by the new wage of  $12per hour equals $400 of total income). A fourth choice would involve less income and much more leisure at a point like Point D, with a choice like 50 hours of leisure, 20 hours of work, and $240 in income.

In effect, Vivian can choose whether to receive the benefits of her wage increase in the form of more income, or more leisure, or some mixture of these two. With this range of possibilities, it would be unwise to assume that Vivian (or anyone else) will necessarily react to a wage increase by working substantially more hours. Maybe they will; maybe they will not.

Applications of Utility Maximizing with the Labour-Leisure Budget Constraint

The theoretical insight that higher wages will sometimes cause an increase in hours worked, sometimes cause hours worked not to change by much, and sometimes cause hours worked to decline, has led to labour supply curves that look like the one in Figure 4.3b. The bottom-left portion of the labour supply curve slopes upward, which reflects the situation of a person who reacts to a higher wage by supplying a greater quantity of labour. The middle, close-to-vertical portion of the labour supply curve reflects the situation of a person who reacts to a higher wage by supplying about the same quantity of labour. The very top portion of the labour supply curve is called a backward-bending supply curve for labour, which is the situation of high-wage people who can earn so much that they respond to a still-higher wage by working fewer hours. Read the following Clear It Up feature for more on the number of hours the average person works each year.

Figure 4.3b. A Backward-Bending Supply Curve of Labour. A Backward-Bending Supply Curve of Labour by OpenStax, licensed under CC BY 4.0.

Figure 4.3b. A Backward-Bending Supply Curve of Labour has the vertical axis is wage and horizontal axis is hours of labour. The bottom upward-sloping portion of the labour supply curve shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked also increases. The middle, nearly vertical portion of the labour supply curve shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked changes very little. The backward-bending portion of the labour supply curve at the top shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked actually decreases. All three of these possibilities can be derived from how a change in wages causes movement in the labour-leisure budget constraint, and thus different choices by individuals.

Example 6.4.1: Is America a nation of workaholics?

Americans work a lot. Table 4.3c shows average hours worked per year in the United States, Canada, Japan, and several European countries, with data from 2013. To get a perspective on these numbers, someone who works 40 hours per week for 50 weeks per year, with two weeks off, would work 2,000 hours per year. The gap in hours worked is a little astonishing; the 250 to 300 hour gap between how much Americans work and how much Germans or the French work amounts to roughly six to seven weeks less of work per year. Economists who study these international patterns debate the extent to which average Americans and Japanese have a preference for working more than, say, Germans, or whether German workers and employers face particular kinds of taxes and regulations that lead to fewer hours worked. Many countries have laws that regulate the work week and dictate holidays and the standards of “normal” vacation time vary from country to country. It is also interesting to take the amount of time spent working in context; it is estimated that in the late nineteenth century in the United States, the average work week was over 60 hours per week—leaving little to no time for leisure.

Table 4.3c: Average Hours Worked Per Year in Select Countries(Source: Organization For Economic Co-Operation And Development [OECD], n.d.)
Country Average Annual Hours Actually Worked per Employed Person
United States 1,824
Spain 1,799
Japan 1,759
Canada 1,751
United Kingdom 1,669
Sweden 1,585
Germany 1,443
France 1,441

 

 

The different responses to a rise in wages—more hours worked, the same hours worked, or fewer hours worked—are patterns exhibited by different groups of workers in the U.S. economy. Many full-time workers have jobs where the number of hours is held relatively fixed, partly by their own choice and partly by their employer’s practices. These workers do not much change their hours worked as wages rise or fall, so their supply curve of labour is inelastic. However, part-time workers and younger workers tend to be more flexible in their hours, and more ready to increase hours worked when wages are high or cut back when wages fall.

The backward-bending supply curve for labour, when workers react to higher wages by working fewer hours and having more income, is not observed often in the short run. However, some well-paid professionals, like dentists or accountants, may react to higher wages by choosing to limit the number of hours, perhaps by taking especially long vacations, or taking every other Friday off. Over a long-term perspective, the backward-bending supply curve for labour is common. Over the last century, Americans have reacted to gradually rising wages by working fewer hours; for example, the length of the average work-week has fallen from about 60 hours per week in 1900 to the present average of less than 40 hours per week.

Recognizing that workers have a range of possible reactions to a change in wages casts some fresh insight on a perennial political debate: the claim that a reduction in income taxes—which would, in effect, allow people to earn more per hour—will encourage people to work more. The leisure-income budget set points out that this connection will not hold true for all workers. Some people, especially part-timers, may react to higher wages by working more. Many will work the same number of hours. Some people, especially those whose incomes are already high, may react to the tax cut by working fewer hours. Of course, cutting taxes may be a good or a bad idea for a variety of reasons, not just because of its impact on work incentives, but the specific claim that tax cuts will lead people to work more hours is only likely to hold for specific groups of workers and will depend on how and for whom taxes are cut.

Key Concepts and Summary

When making a choice along the labour-leisure budget constraint, a household will choose the combination of labour, leisure, and income that provides the most utility. The result of a change in wage levels can be higher work hours, the same work hours, or lower work hours.

Attribution

Except where otherwise noted, this chapter (text and images) is adapted from  “Labor-Leisure Choices” In ECN-1050: Principles of Microeconomics (LibreTexts) by OpenStax, adapted from Principles of Microeconomics., licensed under CC BY 4.0. 

Original Source References

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2022a, June 03). Table B-2. Average weekly hours and overtime of all employees on private nonfarm payrolls by industry sector, seasonally adjusted [Economic Press Release]. https://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.t18.htm

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2022b, June 16).  Employer costs for employee compensation: March 2022 [New Release]. https://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/ecec.pdf

Organization For Economic Co-Operation And Development [OECD]. (n.d.). Average annual hours actually worked per worker [Data Set].  stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=ANHRS

Media Attributions

definition

License

Icon for the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License

Labour Economics for Leaders Copyright © 2023 by Norm Smith, Georgian College is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, except where otherwise noted.

Share This Book