2.8 – Opportunity Costs & Sunk Costs
Learning Objectives
- Understand the three step process for making binary decisions
- Calculate the opportunity cost of an action
- Understand how sunk costs influence our decision making
Economics looks at how rational individuals make decisions. An important part of being a rational decision maker is considering opportunity costs. In our introductory section we identified the concept of scarcity. Normally we are quite good at considering scarcity when it comes to resources and money. What we are less good at considering is scarcity of time.
Consider the following image that shows the number of weeks an average human lives. Sometimes it kind of feels like our lives are made up of a countless number of weeks. But there they are—fully countable—staring you in the face. This isn’t meant to scare you, but rather to emphasize that a rational consumer doesn’t ignore time, but incorporates it into the analysis of any decision they make.
So how do you ‘spend’ your time? In economics, we want to place a value on each different opportunity we have so we can compare them.
What if your friends were to ask you if you want to go out to the club? How much do you value it? As economists, we want to measure the happiness you will get from this experience by finding your maximum willingness to pay. Let’s say that for a 5 hour night at the club, the MOST you are willing to pay is $100. Seem high? If you have gone clubbing, this is likely close to what you paid for it.
Suppose the costs of going clubbing are $50 ($15 cover, $20 for drinks and $15 for a ride home). With that analysis it seems like you should go, but so far we have only considered the explicit costs of the experience. An explicit cost represents a clear direct payment of cash (whether actual cash or from debit, credit, etc). But what about our time? We must consider time as another cost of the action.
How do we measure time? Simple – what else could we be doing with that time? Assume you also work as a server at the campus pub, where you get paid $15 an hour (including tips). This makes it easy to put a dollar amount on your time. For 5 hours of clubbing, you are forgoing the opportunity to earn [latex]{\scriptsize\$75 (\$15 \times 5)}[/latex]. This is your implicit cost for clubbing, or the cost that has been incurred but does not result in a direct payment.
It is important to note that the implicit costs are the benefit of the next best option. There are an infinite number of things we could be doing with our time, from watching a movie to studying economics, but for implicit costs we only consider the next best. If we took them all into account our costs would be infinite.
Consider the two options side by side as shown in Table 2.8a.
Table 2.8a Comparison between clubbing and working Text Version
Table 2.8a depicts the side by side comparison between clubbing and working to illustrate explicit costs. The equation is the Willingness to Pay/Total Benefit + Explicit Costs = Total ‘Happiness’ where clubbing is [latex]{\scriptsize\$100 - \$50 = \$50}[/latex]and working is [latex]{\scriptsize\$75 - \$0 = \$75}[/latex].
Clubbing | Working | |
---|---|---|
Willingness to Pay/Total Benefit | $100 | $75 |
Explicit Costs | $50 | $0 |
Total ‘Happiness’ | $50 | $75 |
Table 2.8aThis shows us something interesting. Even though we are willing to pay $100 to go out clubbing, our ‘happiness’ from working is greater. A rational consumer would chose to work. The $75 we could be earning from working is equal to our implicit costs of going out since, rather than going clubbing, we could be making money for the 5 hours. To truly consider costs we must always consider our opportunity costs which include the implicit and explicit costs of an action.
Table 2.8b Opportunity cost with clubbing and working Text Version
Table 2.8 b considers the opportunity cost with clubbing and working. We have decided to choose the clubbing option (even though it is irrational). Using the same data as Table 2.8a add the Explicit Costs from the Clubbing column and the Total ‘Happiness’ from the Working column to obtain the Opportunity Costs. In other words Explicit Costs (cover, drinks and ride home) + Implicit Costs (forgone income from 5 hours) = Opportunity Costs. [latex]{\scriptsize\$50 + \$75 = \$125}[/latex].
Clubbing ($) | Working ($) | |
---|---|---|
Willingness to Pay/Total Benefit | $100 | $75 |
Explicit Costs | $50 | $0 |
Total ‘Happiness’ | $50 | $75 |
In this example if you were to go clubbing opportunity costs are: Explicit Costs (cover, drinks and ride home) $50 Implicit Costs (forgone income from 5 hours) : $75 Opportunity Costs : $125 Should you go clubbing? You are only willing to pay $100, and your opportunity costs are $125 so no! Does this mean you should never go out? Not at all. You just may be surprised that your willingness to pay may be well over $100.
How to measure ‘Happiness’
In our previous analysis we refer to the concept of “Total Happiness.” The problem is, happiness is not an easy value to measure. Daniel Bernoulli, an economist, first introduced the concept of utility as a means of measuring happiness. Classical economists will often assume that utilities can be measured as a hard number. In reality, it is must harder to measure the happiness a consumer receives from a good. Often, we will use the measurement of how much a consumer is willing to pay, but even this information can be difficult to assess. For the remainder of Topic 1, we will refer to happiness as something that can be measured, recognizing that this is rarely as easy as it will appear here.
Scarcity
This consideration of opportunity cost is rooted in an understanding that all resources are scarce. The first image paints a compelling picture of the scarcity of time, and our financial resources are also scarce. Being a rational decision maker means considering the scarcity of all resources associated with an action. As decision makers, we have to make trade-offs on what we do with finite resources.
This leads us to a fairly simple conclusion. We should do something if the benefits outweigh the costs. The key insight is that the costs we are referring to are opportunity costs, which consider the next best alternative use of our resources.
Making Decisions
We have now looked at how to analyze two options, but how do we make the decision? We can lay the process out in three steps:
- Find your willingness to pay (or wage you would earn) from the option you are considering and the next best alternative
- Subtract the explicit costs from each option to find your happiness
- Choose the option with that makes you happier
If we want to change this into the process for a binary decision (yes or no):
- Add up all the benefits of an action
- Subtract all costs explicit and implicit
- If benefits > costs, this is the right choice
It is important to note that not all decisions are binary.
Sunk Costs
Just as it is important to understand the costs that should be considered in decision making, it is important to understand what costs should not. Consider the two options you may have when you wake up – do you work out or sleep in? Have you ever convinced yourself to get out of bed by reminding yourself that you paid $60 for your monthly gym membership? Well, you fell victim to a common logical fallacy.
A sunk cost is a cost that no matter what is unrecoverable. As such it should have no impact on future decision making. This may sound strange, but consider the your two options using the analysis learned above for making decisions.
The Table2.8c above, Sunk Costs Work-Out vs. Sleep-In, depicts the side by side comparison between working out and sleeping in to illustrate sunk costs. Following our steps we find the maximum willingness to pay for each option, subtract the explicit costs, and compare the happiness from each. Working-out would be[latex]{\scriptsize \$20 - \$0 = \$20}[/latex] and Sleeping-in would be [latex]{\scriptsize\$30 - \$0 = \$30}[/latex]; therefore, Sleeping-in would provide more happiness. It does not matter that we spend $60 on a gym membership because no matter what we do we can’t get that money back. With this willingness to pay reflected in the table, the better option is to Sleep-In, with an opportunity cost of $20.
Notice that the $60 is not included as an explicit costs because it is not an additional cost we have to incur as a result of working out. Since we have already paid the $60, it is no longer something we consider.
Why Buy a Gym Membership?
Why would one ever buy a gym membership? Well in this case, it might be a bad idea. The ‘willingness to pay’ represents how badly someone might want to go to the gym. If you knew that every morning you would wake up and value sleeping more than working out, then a gym pass might not be for you.
If that was the case you would need to find a way to increase your willingness to go to the gym, for example, if you committed to a work out plan with a friend, the social cost of sleeping in may be high, incentivizing you to get out of bed.
The important lesson here is to be mindful of your future motivation when you are incurring a sunk cost.
Sunk Costs & Business
Sunk costs aren’t exclusive to gym memberships, in fact, the sunk cost fallacy is common in big business and government. Ever heard the expression “we’ve invested too much in this project to back out now?” Even if you have not, it sounds fairly logical – unfortunately it is not.
Consider a mining company that has invested $5 million in the infrastructure of a mine. After new information, they learn of another, richer mine site that they can mine for $4million, with projected revenues of $8 million. The current mine site will cost $1 million to extract the remaining resources ($4 million projected revenue). What should the company do?
Table 2.8d. Table of sunk costs and business comparing continuing to mine and mining in a new site Text version
Continue Mining | Mine in a New Site | |
---|---|---|
Investment in Project to Date | $5 million | No figure available |
Project Revenues | $4 million | $8 million |
Explicit Costs | $1 million | $4 million |
Total Profits | $3 million | $4 million |
Investment in Project to Date is reflective of sunk costs: $5 million to continue mining and an unknown figure to mine in a new site.
Project revenues subtract explicit costs equal the total profits for the project. As shown the total profits from the new site are higher, so despite the fact they have invested $5 million in the old site, they should abandon it and mine the new. The conclusion: sunk costs are irrelevant for decision making.
Exercises 1.2
- Which of the following statements about opportunity cost is TRUE?
- Opportunity cost is equal to implicit costs plus explicit costs.
- Opportunity cost only measures direct monetary costs.
- Opportunity cost accounts for alternative uses of resources such as time and money.
- I, II and III.
- I
- III only.
- I and III only.
- Which of the following statements about opportunity costs is TRUE?
- I. The opportunity cost of a given action is equal to the value foregone of all feasible alternative actions.
- II. Opportunity costs only measure direct out of pocket expenditures.
- III. To calculate accurately the opportunity cost of an action we need to first identify the next best alternative to that action.
- III only.
- I and III only.
- II only.
- None of the statements is true.
- Suppose that you deciding between seeing a move and going to a concert on a particular Saturday evening. You are willing to pay $20 to see the movie and the movie ticket costs $5. You are willing to pay $80 for the concert and the concert ticket costs $50. The opportunity cost of going to the movie is:
- $5
- $30
- $35
- $65
- Suppose that you are willing to pay $20 to see a movie on Saturday night. A ticket costs $10, and the next-best alternative use of your time would be to go to dinner with a friend. The cost of the dinner is $20 and you value the experience of having dinner with your friend at $60. The opportunity cost of seeing the movie is equal to:
- $50
- $30
- $20
- $10
- Suppose that you are willing to pay $50 to see a movie on Saturday night. A ticket costs $15 , and the next-best alternative use of your time would be to go to a concert which costs $80 and you value at $100. The opportunity cost of seeing the movie is equal to:
- $15
- $20
- $35
- $70
- Suppose you play a round of golf costing $75. The golf takes four hours to play. If you were not playing golf you could be working and earning $40 per hour. The opportunity cost of your golf game is:
- $75.
- $235.
- $155.
- $160.
- Suppose you have bought and paid for a ticket to see Lady Gaga in concert. You were willing to pay up to $200 for this ticket, but it only cost you $110. On the day of the concert, a friend offers you a free ticket to the opera instead. Assuming that it is impossible to resell the Lady Gaga ticket, what is the minimum value you would have to place on a night at the opera, in order for you to choose the opera over Lady Gaga?
- $200.
- $110.
- $90.
- $0.
- Suppose that you are willing to pay $350 to see Leonard Cohen play at the Save-On-Foods Arena. Tickets cost $100, and the next-best alternative use of your time would be to work in paid employment earning $50 over the evening. The opportunity cost of seeing Leonard Cohen is equal to:
- $50.
- $100.
- $150.
- $200.
- I am considering loaning my brother $10,000 for one year. He has agreed to pay 10% interest on the loan. If I don’t loan my brother the $10,000, it will stay in my bank account for the year, where it will earn 2% interest. What is the opportunity cost to me of the loan to my brother?
- $200.
- $800.
- $1,000.
- $1,200.
- In January, in an attempt to commit to getting fit, I signed a year-long, binding contract at a local gym, agreeing to pay $40 per month in membership fees. I also spent $300 on extremely stylish gym clothes. This morning, I was trying to decide whether or not to actually go to the gym. Which of the following was relevant to this decision?
- The $40 that I paid the gym this month.
- The $300 I spent on gym clothes.
- The fact that I also had to write a 103 midterm exam today.
- All of the above were relevant.
- Suppose you have bought and paid for a ticket to see Kanye in concert. You were willing to pay up to $350 for this ticket, but it only cost you $100. On the day of the concert, a friend offers you a free ticket to Lady Gaga instead. You can resell your Kanye ticket for $80. What do your sunk costs equal?
- $0.
- $20.
- $80.
- $100.
- As a member of UVic’s University Club, I pay $30 per month in membership fees. In a typical month I spend about $50 on beer at the Club. Every month I also have the option of attending a meeting of the whiskey club (open only to Club members), at a cost per meeting of $15, payable at the beginning of each meeting. Given this, what do my monthly SUNK COSTS equal?
- $15.
- $30.
- $45.
- $95.
Check your answer[1]
Attribution
Except where otherwise noted, this chapter is adapted from “Opportunity Costs & Sunk Costs” and “Topic 1 Solutions” In Principles of Microeconomics by Dr. Emma Hutchinson, University of Victoria licesnsed under CC BY 4.0. / A derivative of Principles of Economics (OpenStax) by Steven A. Greenlaw, Timothy Taylor, licesensed under CC BY 2.0. /Adaptations include removal of:
- image describing spending/ scheduling time throughout your life
- removal of question 12 from Exercises 1.2.
Access for free at Principles of Microeconomics 2e
Original Source Chapter References
Dehaas, Josh. Macleans. “Professors pay ranked highest to lowest.” May 4, 2012. http://www.macleans.ca/education/uniandcollege/professor-pay-ranked-from-highest-to-lowest/
Jeevanandam, Vimala. The Ring. “Buzz builds over beer chemistry collaboration.” November 3, 2016. https://www.uvic.ca/ring/news/research/2016+brewery-yeast-hof+ring
Investopedia. “Utility.” http://www.investopedia.com/terms/u/utility.asp
Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. March 9, 1776.
Statistics Canada. “Labour Force Characteristics.” 2016. http://www.statcan.gc.ca/tables-tableaux/sum-som/l01/cst01/econ10-eng.htm
Urban, Tim. Wait But Why. “Your Life in Weeks.” May 7, 2014. http://waitbutwhy.com/2014/05/life-weeks.html
Media Attributions
- Image © Dr. Emma Hutchinson, University of Victoria is licensed under a CC BY (Attribution) license
- Image © Dr. Emma Hutchinson, University of Victoria is licensed under a CC BY (Attribution) license
- Image © Dr. Emma Hutchinson, University of Victoria is licensed under a CC BY (Attribution) license
- Image © Scott Webb
- Image © Dr. Emma Hutchinson, University of Victoria is licensed under a CC BY (Attribution) license
- Question 1) D , Question 2) A , Question 3) C , Question 4) A , Question 5) C , Question 6) B , Question 7) A , Question 8) C , Question 9)A , Question 10) C , Question 11) B , Question 12) B ↵
all costs associated with an action, both explicit and implicit
the direct cost of an action, usually involves a cash transaction or a physical transfer of resources.
a sacrifice of resources (time, money etc.) to achieve a certain benefit
the maximum amount of resources a consumer is willing to lose to achieve a certain benefit
Costs that we make in the past that we cannot recover